Advanced Macroeconomics
Fall 2015

Follow-ups and comments on different issues

 

23/9    After the lecture yesterday I was asked to focus more on two things: actual policy issues and data. As to the first, I agree that the models are not goals in themselves but analytical tools useful for explanation of macroeconomic mechanisms and evaluation of alternative policies. A full understanding of the models is necessary for being able to apply them in precise economic analysis.
    As to data and empirics: yes, empirical evidence is important. Therefore, from the empirical literature we pick up numbers to be connected to key parameters. And there are references in the lecture notes to relevant empirical material. Sometimes there are also links at the lecture webside to "data".
    Yet the course is primarily about theory, models and methods for their application. Nevertheless, when I for instance sketch the main ides in Barro's dynasty model and for lack of time do not say much about the empirics, this does not mean that you can not find at least some empirics in the lecture notes. In the Barro case you can find some at p. 255-56 and p. 274-76. In addition, in Elmendorf and Mankiw (on the agenda 20th of Oct.) there is a survey on empirical literature concerning the Ricardian equivalence issue. And here there are links to more.

23/9    In the list of possible supplementary textbooks in the course plan, I have forgotten Ben J. Heijdra: Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics, OUP 2009, http://www.heijdra.org/fomm2.htm. This book is a useful attempt at bridging the gap between bachelor course texts and PhD course texts.

30/9    An example of Danish empirics of relevance for the controversy about Ricardian Equivalence or Non-equivalence:
C. T. Kreiner, D. D. Lassen and S. Leth-Petersen (2014), Liquidity Constraint Tightness and Consumer Responses to Fiscal Stimulus Policy. Working Paper.

20/10    In today's lecture a good question was raised from the audience about the Ricardian Non-equivalence issue as discussed in the lecture notes, Section 13.1. Although I have not discovered clear errors in the text, I admit that the exposition was not well written. The first six pages of the chapter has therefore been rewritten. The new version of these pages is here. The remainder of the chapter is unchanged. Nevertheless, here is the chapter as whole with the revised first six pages inserted.

27/10    In today's discussion of issues in debt policy I presented a table with anti-fiscal policy views in the left column and Keynesian counter arguments in the right column. Row 3 in the table mentioned Ricardian equivalence in the left column and Ricardian Non-equivalence in the right column. In relation to this, I just want to mention that at the exam in January 15, 2014, Problem 3 was about whether expansionary fiscal policy may succeed being expansionary even if the household sector consists of Barro-style dynasty households with infinite horizon, taxes are lump sum, and credit markets are perfect. This issue may give an additional perspective on the discussion.

2/11    A reference in Ch. 14, p. 597, to Groth and Madsen (2013), is to this paper (from May 2015 = most recent version).

8/11    1. A question from the floor in today's lecture about the fundamental house price and a hypothetical price bubble lead me to review Appendix C of Ch. 15 and slightly extend the last paragraph in this way.
        2.
As briefly touched upon also in today's lecture, rational expectations should be seen as a benchmark case. On alternatives to rational expectations, see e.g.:
    Fuster, Laibson, and Mendel, Natural expectations and macroeconomic fluctuations, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 24, no. 4, Fall 2010.
    More in Supplementary material.

11/11    Follow-up on hysteresis in employment and unemployment, cf. Midterm Paper Problem 1: See, e.g., DeLong, J. B., and L. H. Summers, Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy [with Comments and Discussion], Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2012, 233-297. Includes discussion by Martin Feldstein and Valerie Ramey.
    See also
Ball, DeLong, and Summers (2014), Fiscal policy and full employment. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, April 2, 2014.

17/11    Concerning Problem 1e)-h) in the Midterm problem set, the following question, as I understood it, was raised from the floor: Could there not be dynamic output effects across periods from the expansionary fiscal policy during the slump, and if so, why are they not taken into account. I agree that the text should have said explicitly that such possible effects are ignored. The motivation for ignoring them is twofold. First, such effects are uncertain and difficult to assess. Second, an exercise problem should not be too complex. This is also the reason, that under the expansionary fiscal policy the slump is assumed over after only two periods.   

7/12    Question 1: Saddle-point stability was defined in a lecture I could not attend. How is it defined?
Answer: Here is the definition.
    Question 2: The course plan, also the final version, has under point 5.2 a topic named "the interplay of nominal and real price rigidities". Where in syllabus is that topic treated?
Answer: Almost nowhere! It is a mistake that topic was not deleted in the final version of the course plan. It is only briefly touched on in Ch. 19, p. 728, point 2), and p. 759. Those interested may read Section 6.6 in D. Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, 4th. edition, available from the faculty library.

16/12    Question 3: Chapter 14, p.581: Is it correct that

  ?

CG : Yes, but only if the maximized value of the right-hand side is meant. That is what the asterisk on the left-hand side indicates.

 

 Question 4: Chapter 15:

I don’t think I really understand what α and S_t are.  In the note p. 628 you write S_t is the number of square meter-months at disposal for utilization, but I don’t understand what square meter-months mean. If H_t = 100 m2 floor area

 CG: That is not the case. H_t is the aggregate number of “standard-sized” houses at time t, a stock. H_t could be 2 million “standard-sized” houses.

where t is a year,

 CG: No, t is a point in time, a year is a time interval.

 it implies (as far as I understand)  so , but what does this number mean?

 CG: There is here a misunderstanding. Alpha is the flow of housing services per year of a “standard-sized” house. Let a “standard-sized” house be a house of  floor area, and let the unit of a housing service be “access to  floor area in a month”. Now, alpha is the housing service per house per year, since the time unit of the model is one year. That is, alpha = units of housing services. So    units of housing services.

 And what does it mean (on p. 629) that “…one unit of housing service per year to mean disposal of a house of standard size one year”?

CG: It means we normalize alpha to be one. That is, we let one unit of floor area be    and one time unit be 1 year.

31/12    Question 5: Also Chapter 15: Page 636 it’s written that “Due to the positive relationship between building productivity and H, the marginal building costs are unchanged in the medium run”. Why is this so, or in what equation can I see it?

CG: “…in the medium run” here means in steady state. But the steady state shifts if a tax changes, cf. Fig. 15.10. Nevertheless, marginal building costs in any of the possible steady states are the same and equals the unchanged p*.  How is that possible? It is possible, because the transformation function T  is homogeneous of degree one, see p. 635, the line right above eq. (15.55).

This is the logic. But I agree, it is not well expressed in the text. Indeed, p. 636, line 10-11, starting with “Due to …” should read: “Due to the specific form of the positive relationship between building productivity and H, implied by the transformation function T  being homogeneous of degree one in I and H, the marginal” (additions are in read). This now also appears under Errata to Lecture Notes.

Question 6: Also Chapter 15: pages 637/638: “This price level is constant as long as technical progress in the production of intermediate goods for construction follows the general trend in the economy”? In what equation can I see that this holds?

CG: First, that p* is constant follows from answer to Question 5. Second, p* is a real price and equals real marginal costs in steady state. A real price is a nominal price divided by a relevant price index, the deflator. The deflator could be the consumer price index or the GDP deflator. Suppose, it is here the latter. Then the relative price p* will tend not to change if technical progress in the production of intermediate goods for construction follows the general trend in the economy. Indeed, in that case production costs of intermediate goods for construction will tend to follow the general trend of productions costs in the economy.

1/1-2016    Here is a follow-up (also written in Absalon) on one of Marias' questions in Discussion Forum in Absalon. The last question from Maria was:

"Also, in exercise VI.4.g is the following correct?
Higher r increases the rate of return to safe bonds, therefore q, the market value of the capital, decreases in order to ensure that the rate of return on the existing capital stock increases correspondingly."

As a supplement to the Niklas' answer I would like to add a general point related to method:

I recommend that you always keep in mind whether a given exercise problem is within partial equilibrium analysis or general equilibrium analysis. The present problem, Exercise VI.4, is throughout, including question g), within partial equilibrium analysis: a single firm's value maximization s.t. constraints involving market parameters that are exogenous to the firm. 

The firm faces a given downward-sloping demand curve (**), and question g) is just about how the firm, being initially in a steady state, responds if the interest rate shifts to a higher level, thereby making the past steady state obsolete. How the rise in the interest rate might affect average q in the economy as a whole is an entirely different question and is not something that the firm facing the given downward-sloping demand curve (**) cares about and responds to. 

Similarly, when we describe the Slutsky substitution, income, and wealth effects in a given context, we are just performing partial equilibrium analysis and describe how a single agent responds to shifts in variables that are exogenous to the agent.


 

 

 

Back to lectures.